The economics of war and peace
Motivated by the invasion of Ukraine, this chapter provides an overview of the impact of wars and post-war recoveries over the last two centuries. The most damaging wars see GDP per capita decline by 40 to 70 per cent, while post-war recoveries vary widely. In 29 per cent of cases GDP per capita returns to the trend levels observed in comparator countries without wars within five years, but in almost half of all instances it remains below those levels 25 years after the conflict. Reconstruction is particularly difficult if peace is fragile. Furthermore, even if GDP does recover, there may still be lasting scars affecting labour and capital.
Introduction
This chapter provides an overview of the impact of wars and post-war recoveries over the last two centuries. This analysis is motivated by the invasion of Ukraine, which has led to the largest displacement of people in Europe since the Second World War (see Chapter 2). However, the analysis presented here adopts a broader perspective, looking at the history of armed conflicts – both within states (civil wars) and interstate – and highlighting a number of common trends in the data.
A novel dataset
This chapter constructs a novel database of conflict episodes by combining information from the Correlates of War database with data from several other sources. Data on the financing of wars are taken from the Confronting the Costs of War Project (CCWP), which covers the principal belligerents in all interstate wars lasting more than six months in the period 1823-2003. Socio-economic indicators such as GDP, inflation and fiscal variables are taken from the World Economic Outlook produced by the International Monetary Fund (IMF), Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) and the Maddison Project Database. Information on populations, investment, capital stocks and total factor productivity (TFP) comes from the Penn World Tables (which cover the period from 1950 onwards).
Wars have become less common overall since the 1990s
The percentage of economies that are involved in interstate wars spiked around the time of the First and Second World Wars and has fallen in recent decades (see Chart 1.1). Civil wars now account for a larger share of total wars, following a peak in the 1990s.3
Source: Correlates of War and authors’ calculations.
Note: Percentages are based on the Correlates of War database’s definition of countries.
Source: Correlates of War and authors’ calculations.
Note: For definitions of the start and end dates of a war, see the Correlates of War database. Since an interstate war will, by definition, involve more than one country, the term “country-war” is used in this chapter to indicate that data describe a single war from the perspective of a single country. It should be noted, too, that the dataset includes territories that are no longer considered to be countries.
Countries at war
This section considers the characteristics of economies in wartime, looking at disruptions to economic activity and examining the ways in which countries finance wars (including the implications for fiscal balances and government debt).
Economies can undergo significant structural shifts in wartime
Economies can undergo significant reorientation during wars. For instance, military spending reached 40 per cent of GDP in the United Kingdom and the United States of America during the First and Second World Wars, while military employment accounted for up to 10 per cent of the population.4 While military production can boost GDP, wars – particularly those fought on a country’s own territory – can also result in significant disruption to economic activity.
Source: Correlates of War, Maddison Project Database and authors’ calculations.
Note: Includes only wars fought on a country’s own territory. “Deepest cumulative drop in GDP per capita” refers to the difference between GDP per capita in the last year before the war and the lowest level of GDP per capita recorded during the war.
Drops in GDP per capita are larger for economies in the EBRD regions
The following analysis compares GDP per capita during a war with a path that could be expected in the absence of war on the basis of a weighted average of the experiences of similar economies that did not experience armed conflict during the relevant period (a “synthetic counterfactual growth path”). The economies that are used to construct this synthetic control are similar to the economy at war in terms of their pre-war GDP per capita at purchasing power parity (PPP), population size and growth.6 Comparator economies are considered in the same year as the economy at war, so the methodology and standard errors take year effects into account.
Source: Correlates of War, Maddison Project Database and authors’ calculations.
Note: Includes only wars fought on a country’s own territory that were not preceded by another war in the previous five years. Comparators are synthetic controls based on economies that were not at war in the five years before or after the war in question. “t-1” denotes the year before the start of the war. 90 per cent confidence intervals are shown.
Contractions in GDP per capita are larger for lost interstate wars and unresolved conflicts
There is no significant difference between a civil war and an interstate war fought on a country’s own territory in terms of the drop in GDP per capita. However, civil wars are followed by more sluggish recoveries. Those wars are twice as long on average (three years), and the conflict is more likely to remain unresolved (29 per cent of cases, compared with 19 per cent for interstate wars). This may, in part, be due to the rapid formation and disintegration of alliances and fractionalisation within them. Evidence from 53 multi-party civil wars suggests that almost half of the original sides in those conflicts suffered some form of internal fractionalisation, and 85 per cent of those wars saw at least one change of alliance, with over half experiencing three or more changes.8
Public opinion, fear of inflation and administrative capacity can all affect how wars are financed
Economies can pay for wars in various ways. Domestic sources of financing can include borrowing (such as war bonds), taxation (through new war taxes, or increased rates for pre-existing taxes) or the printing of money. Foreign financing may take the form of external borrowing, grants or plunder.
Most interstate wars are financed via domestic borrowing
There is significant variation in the manner in which economies pay for wars, with several types of financing typically being used. For instance, while the United Kingdom and the United States of America used high levels of taxation to finance the First World War, France, Russia and the United Kingdom all borrowed both domestically and abroad, while Germany and Russia relied mainly on the printing of money.
Source: CCWP database and authors’ calculations.
Note: For each form of financing, this chart indicates the percentage of interstate wars for which that financing method covered at least half of the cost of the conflict. It is based on country-years with a single war.
Wars are typically inflationary
In the median interstate war on a country’s own territory, inflation increases by 8 percentage points relative to its pre-war trend (see Chart 1.6). (The inflationary pressures that have been observed in Ukraine in 2022 – which are due in part to the disruption of production and logistics – are broadly in line with this median historical increase.) Meanwhile, average inflation spikes to stand at several hundred per cent, driven by episodes of hyperinflation in the dataset.
Source: Correlates of War, IMF, Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) and authors’ calculations.
Note: Includes only wars fought on a country’s own territory that were not preceded by another war in the previous five years. Comparators are synthetic controls based on economies that were not at war in the five years before or after the war in question.
Wars result in a significant build-up of sovereign debt
Government revenue drops during wars as economic activity collapses, although in some cases it later recovers because of investment in fiscal capacity and the introduction of new taxes. Meanwhile, government expenditure rises and fiscal balances tend to worsen: on average, primary deficits increase by about 5 percentage points relative to before the war (see Chart 1.7). These patterns tend to be more muted for civil wars.
Source: Correlates of War, IMF and authors’ calculations.
Note: Includes only wars fought on a country’s own territory that were not preceded by another war in the previous five years. Given the shorter time series available, comparators are a simple average of economies that were not at war in the five years before or after the war in question. 90 per cent confidence intervals are shown.
Source: Correlates of War, IMF and authors’ calculations.
Note: Includes only wars fought on a country’s own territory that were not preceded by another war in the previous five years. Given the shorter time series available, comparators are a simple average of economies that were not at war in the five years before or after the war in question. 90 per cent confidence intervals are shown.
After a war, debt is often restructured or inflated away
Fiscal consolidation is seldom used to pay for past conflicts, as wars tend, on average, to be followed by primary fiscal deficits, which contribute to a further build-up of government debt. However, inflation often helps to erode the value of debt accumulated during wars. In around 60 per cent of cases, wars result in inflation rising above pre-war levels.
Source: Bank of Canada-Bank of England Sovereign Default Database, Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) and authors’ calculations.
Note: This chart shows the probability of a country experiencing default or restructuring in a given year (provided that it was not in default or experiencing restructuring in the previous year). The comparator group of economies at peace are economies that were not at war in the five years before or after the year in question.
External imbalances widen during wars
Exports and imports both fall sharply as a share of GDP during wars (see also Chapter 3), before largely rebounding after the conflict has ended.17 External deficits widen during interstate wars on a country’s own territory, increasing by an average of 5 percentage points of GDP relative to pre-war levels on account of a collapse in exports (which is, in part, mitigated by a contraction in imports as aggregate demand collapses; see Chart 1.10).
Source: Correlates of War, IMF and authors’ calculations.
Note: Includes only wars fought on a country’s own territory that were not preceded by another war in the previous five years. Given the shorter time series available, comparators are a simple average of economies that were not at war in the five years before or after the war in question. 90 per cent confidence intervals are shown.
Investment falls during wars and remains subdued after civil wars
Investment declines as a share of GDP during wars, falling by around 1 to 2.5 percentage points on average relative to its pre-war level, reflecting general economic disruption and increased uncertainty (see Chart 1.11). Capital flight can also reduce the savings that are available to fund investment.18 Investment remains lower for longer after civil wars, probably reflecting higher levels of uncertainty, as these conflicts are more likely to remain unresolved or be followed by another war.19
Source: Correlates of War, Penn World Tables and authors’ calculations.
Note: Includes only wars fought on a country’s own territory that were not preceded by another war in the previous five years. Comparators are synthetic controls based on economies that were not at war in the five years before or after the war in question.
Source: Correlates of War, World Bank and authors’ calculations.
Note: Includes only wars fought on a country’s own territory that were not preceded by another war in the previous five years. Given the shorter time series available, comparators are a simple average of economies that were not at war in the five years before or after the war in question. 90 per cent confidence intervals are shown.
Post-war recovery and reconstruction: lessons from the past
This section looks at post-war recoveries, summarising key lessons from past reconstruction episodes.
Reconstruction episodes vary widely
Not only is there significant variation in patterns of economic activity during wars, recoveries also vary tremendously, even accounting for variation in economic damage. Sometimes (as in the case of Italy after the Second World War) growth accelerates significantly compared with the pre-war trend. In other instances (such as Egypt in the 1970s), the economy returns to its synthetic counterfactual growth path within a few years of the war ending. In many other cases, recoveries take decades. For instance, Japan’s reconstruction after the Second World War, which is often held up as an example of successful rebuilding, saw the country take 15 years to return to the GDP per capita trend observed in comparator economies. In some cases, GDP per capita never returns to the trend levels observed in comparators (as seen, for example, in Iran after the Iran-Iraq War of the 1980s). Recoveries are particularly slow where they are interrupted by further wars (as in the case of Greece’s recovery after the First World War, which was interrupted by the Second World War and a civil war).
Source: Correlates of War, IMF, Maddison Project Database and authors’ calculations.
Note: This chart indicates the cumulative percentage of economies that took t years or less to reach the level of GDP per capita that would be expected on the basis of the economic growth of their comparators (which are economies that were not at war in the five years before or after the war in question). Wars that are followed by less than 25 years of data are excluded.
Recoveries are slower after civil wars and in economies with weaker pre-war growth
The following analysis looks at how the length of the post-war recovery is correlated with conditions before the war (the strength of economic growth and the quality of democratic institutions), the severity, length and nature of the war, and the reoccurrence of hostilities after the initial conflict ends.21 The quality of democratic institutions is captured by indices taken from the Varieties of Democracy (V-Dem) database, which provides multi-dimensional measures of democracy for 202 economies (going as far back as 1789 in some cases).
- Economies that recovered within 10 years
- Economies that did not recover within 10 years
Source: Correlates of War, IMF, V-Dem database and authors’ calculations.
Note: This chart shows simple averages for (i) economies where GDP per capita returned within 10 years to the trend levels that could be expected on the basis of the experiences of comparator economies and (ii) economies where GDP per capita did not return to those levels within 10 years. A “repeat war” is another war taking place within five years of the end of the original conflict.
Reconstruction is more difficult if peace is fragile
Reconstruction is more difficult after protracted, unresolved conflicts and fragile settlements, as the threat of a return to conflict and continued security issues increase the cost of reconstruction (as seen, for instance, in Afghanistan and Iraq).23
Source: Correlates of War and authors’ calculations.
Note: Wars that are followed by less than 25 years of data are excluded.
External aid can support reconstruction, provided there is sufficient administrative capacity
Damage to infrastructure and other assets can be extensive, equivalent to two or three times pre-conflict GDP, and external aid can play an important role in supporting reconstruction. The US government spent 2 per cent of the country’s GDP on the Marshall Plan (equivalent to US$ 450 billion today) after the Second World War, which was widely credited with supporting post-war recovery and technological development in European economies (see Box 1.2). After the 1990-91 war in Kuwait, petroleum production and refinery capacity exceeded pre-war levels by 1994 thanks to extensive use of foreign contractors.24
The “new normal”
This last part of the chapter uses a production-function approach to look at whether wars cause long lasting changes to the structure of economies. In contrast with previous sections, the focus here is not on flows (such as the value added that is produced each year) but on damage to the stocks of resources that are available to the economy in the long term, such as human and physical capital. This section also looks at whether wars result in meaningful improvements to economic and political institutions, as well as the administrative and fiscal capacity of the state.
The labour force tends to shrink after a war
Wars have long-lasting effects on countries’ populations, reflecting casualties, outflows of refugees (see Chapter 2) and declining birth rates. Population growth typically drops by around 1.5 percentage points during wars (relative to comparator economies that are not at war) and remains 0.5 percentage point lower five years after the end of the war. Thus, populations remain permanently smaller (see Chart 1.16), with the impact of a war being visible as much as 25 years after the end of the conflict. For instance, 10 years after the end of the First World War, the populations of France, Germany and the United Kingdom were all still smaller than they had been in 1913, while the populations of neutral Denmark, The Netherlands and Spain were between 13 and 24 per cent higher than their pre-war levels.
Source: Correlates of War, Penn World Tables and authors’ calculations.
Note: Includes only wars fought on a country’s own territory that were not preceded by another war in the previous five years. Comparators are synthetic controls based on economies that were not at war in the five years before or after the war in question. 90 per cent confidence intervals are shown.
Wars result in lasting damage to capital stocks
Wars also reduce capital stocks (including all capital involved in production, such as factories, equipment and agricultural land), as existing capital is destroyed during wars or taken out of the country, while investment in new capital may remain subdued, as discussed earlier (see also Box 1.4). For instance, Mozambique’s railway network lost more than 90 per cent of its rolling stock during the country’s 1977 civil war.33 Capital stocks in the United States of America did not recover until 20 years after the 1861 civil war, with agricultural investment in affected areas remaining suppressed for almost 60 years.34 At the end of the Second World War, the capital stocks of France, Germany and Italy were between 20 and 40 per cent lower than they had been in 1939, and they did not return to their pre-war trend levels for another 20 to 25 years.35
Source: Correlates of War, Penn World Tables and authors’ calculations.
Note: Includes only wars fought on a country’s own territory that were not preceded by another war in the previous five years. Comparators are synthetic controls based on economies that were not at war in the five years before or after the war in question. 90 per cent confidence intervals are shown.
Increases in productivity may offset some of the loss of labour and capital
Total factor productivity – a measure of how effectively capital and labour are combined to produce output – drops during wars fought on a country’s own territory, compounding the loss of labour and damage to capital stocks (see Chart 1.18). The initial drop in productivity largely reflects widespread disruption to established production processes.
Source: Correlates of War, Penn World Tables and authors’ calculations.
Note: Includes only wars fought on a country’s own territory that were not preceded by another war in the previous five years. Comparators are synthetic controls based on economies that were not at war in the five years before or after the war in question. 90 per cent confidence intervals are shown.
Can wars make states?
A number of studies have examined the question of whether “wars make states”, as conflicts may accelerate the expansion of fiscal and administrative capacity. Max Weber famously defined a state as “a human community that (successfully) claims the monopoly of the legitimate use of physical force within a given territory”. Indeed, archaeological evidence suggests that the essential functions of the state first emerged when an armed elite, often foreign, sought to collect taxes on output.42 Conquest required administration. The creation of an armed force generated durable state structures, such as treasuries and mechanisms for conscription. Early attempts to broaden the tax base meant that economies started developing censuses and land registries to determine who was taxable, as well as keeping statistical accounts (with GDP becoming the primary economic indicator during the Second World War in order to monitor wartime production).43 Wars in the 20th century were typically associated with sharp increases in the size of the state, in terms of both spending and employment, which were only partly reversed after the end of the conflict.44
Wars may also act as “critical junctures” and promote institutional change. In normal times, institutions are often self-reinforcing via virtuous or vicious circles. In the event of a war, a confluence of factors, such as significant upheaval coupled with a broad coalition of parties pushing for reform, may help to dislodge the existing equilibrium and bring about change – for instance, a transition from extractive institutions to inclusive ones.45
Fiscal and administrative capacity can expand as a result of wars
Improvements in administrative and fiscal capacity are often needed to fund wars. For instance, during the US Civil War revenue from tariffs and customs duties dropped sharply as foreign trade collapsed. This prompted the introduction of the country’s first income tax. Consequently, the percentage of war costs that were financed by taxation tripled during that war. Similarly, the United Kingdom introduced its first general income tax in 1799 to finance its war with France, and Prussia’s tax agency was originally established as The General War Commissariat.46 While Japan was able, in part, to finance the Russo-Japanese War of 1904-05 through taxation, reflecting reforms to its tax system and bureaucratic capacity before the war, low administrative capacity limited Russia’s ability to rely on taxes, necessitating large-scale domestic – and later foreign – borrowing, at a rising cost.47 When Chile went to war in 1865 with access to external finance, its debt-to-GDP ratio grew by 300 percentage points, while its tax ratio remained virtually unchanged. In contrast, when it waged war in 1879 without access to external credit, its tax ratio grew by 75 per cent, reflecting a new income tax and a sharp increase in the tax rate on nitrate exports.48
Early central banks were established as a result of wars
Prior to the use of taxation, borrowing was important for the financing of wars, and that helped to foster the creation of debt markets. For instance, Francis I started borrowing from Parisian businessmen in the 1520s to finance campaigns against the Habsburgs, offering the city’s future revenues as security.49 Similarly, in the first half of the 16th century, the States General of the Habsburg Netherlands took steps towards issuing state-backed annuities secured by specific new taxes, which significantly improved the terms of financing.50
Large institutional improvements are the exception, not the rule
However, quantitative evidence from almost two centuries of wars suggests that, overall, improvements in institutional quality have been rare occurrences. The following analysis examines institutional changes by comparing the quality of democratic institutions (as captured by V-Dem indices) in the five years before a war with the situation seen in the five years after that war. The results of this analysis suggest that large changes in the quality of political institutions (exceeding 1 standard deviation) were observed in less than 10 per cent of cases (with just over half of these being improvements).52
Conclusion
Wars scar economies deeply and post-war recovery paths vary widely. While wars can present opportunities to improve technology or develop better institutions, instances of strong recoveries accompanied by institutional change are the exception rather than the rule. Securing lasting peace is crucial for successful rebuilding – in terms of both physical infrastructure and institutions. Recoveries also tend to be quicker where pre-war growth was stronger and wars are shorter. Past experience suggests that external aid may be more effective where local administrative capacity is strong, where it is front-loaded to provide support in the critical early years of the post-war period, and where grants are combined with lending to limit further increases in government debt. It may also be more effective with domestic ownership and when administered by a dedicated institution, in order to reduce bureaucracy and ensure coordination across different sources. Multi-year planning can allow for the clustering of complementary programmes and longer-term funding of infrastructure investment, while clear sunset provisions can make programmes more politically palatable for donors and minimise “reconstruction fatigue”.
Box 1.1. The impact of armed conflict on firms’ performance
Armed conflicts typically destroy physical infrastructure and human capital, with a devastating impact on individuals and firms.54 Even if firms manage to escape damage to their premises, machinery and equipment, they may still be unable to reach their customers in line with their contractual obligations because of the destruction of infrastructure. They may also face reduced demand for their products as their customers lose income, or they may need to suspend their operations owing to disruption in the supply of intermediate inputs.55 This may reduce expected returns on investment, as well as increasing uncertainty about future revenues, and may, in turn, affect aggregate productivity growth through the reallocation of resources across existing firms, as well as firm entry and exit.56
Box 1.2. Lessons from the Marshall Plan
The Marshall Plan is often held up as the gold standard for internationally funded post-conflict reconstruction programmes. While the amount of financial assistance was relatively limited, other features of the plan – such as its strong show of political support and its conditionality – played an important role in supporting reconstruction.
Box 1.3. Women, war and work: The creation of a “new normal”?
There are few images of war which are as evocative and influential as that of Rosie the Riveter. That familiar figure – a proud, blue-collared female labourer – now adorns everything from mugs to socks, a cultural icon representing all the women who worked in US factories and shipyards during the Second World War. More than 6.5 million women joined the US labour force during the Second World War, increasing female labour force participation by more than 50 per cent.62 American women who filled vacancies created by the exodus of conscripted men were credited with transforming the structure of the country’s labour market.
Box 1.4. Wars and cities
As this chapter has shown, wars inflict lasting damage on capital stocks, despite investment rates gradually recovering post-conflict. This box complements that analysis with evidence of sharp declines in the construction of residential housing during wars and only sluggish recoveries thereafter, with some lasting effects on city structures.
Source: 2017 Euro Survey and authors’ calculations.
References
D. Acemoğlu, D.H. Autor and D. Lyle (2004)
“Women, war, and wages: The effect of female labor supply on the wage structure at midcentury”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 112, No. 3, pp. 497-551.
D. Acemoğlu and J.A. Robinson (2012)
Why nations fail: The origins of power, prosperity and poverty, London: Profile Books Limited.
F. Alvarez-Cuadrado (2008)
“Growth Outside the Stable Path: Lessons from the European Reconstruction”, European Economic Review, Vol. 52, No. 3, pp. 568-588.
Analytics Economics (2022)
“Housing in Ukraine after the war”, Vox Ukraine, 29 April.
J. Antolin-Diaz and P. Surico (2022)
“The Long-Run Effects of Government Spending”, CEPR Discussion Paper No. 17433.
S. Barakat and J. Skelton (2014)
“The reconstruction of post-war Kuwait: A missed opportunity?”, Kuwait Programme on Development, Governance and Globalisation in the Gulf States, No. 37.
R. Barro and J.-W. Lee (2013)
“A New Data Set of Educational Attainment in the World, 1950-2010”, Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 104, pp. 184-198.
T. Becker, B. Eichengreen, Y. Gorodnichenko, S. Guriev, S. Johnson, T. Mylovanov, M. Obstfeld, K. Rogoff and B. Weder di Mauro (2022a)
“Macroeconomic Policies for Wartime Ukraine”, Rapid Response Economics 2, CEPR.
T. Becker, B. Eichengreen, Y. Gorodnichenko, S. Guriev, S. Johnson, T. Mylovanov, K. Rogoff and B. Weder di Mauro (2022b)
“A Blueprint for the Reconstruction of Ukraine”, CEPR.
N. Bianchi and M. Giorcelli (2021)
“Reconstruction Aid, Public Infrastructure, and Economic Development: The Case of the Marshall Plan in Italy”, NBER Working Paper No. 29537.
C. Blattman and E. Miguel (2010)
“Civil war”, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 48, No. 1, pp. 3-57.
M. Bosker, S. Brakman, H. Garretsen and M. Schramm (2007)
“Looking for Multiple Equilibria When Geography Matters: German City Growth and the WWII Shock”, Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 61, No. 1, pp. 152-169.
M. Bosker, S. Brakman, H. Garretsen and M. Schramm (2008)
“A Century of Shocks: The Evolution of the German City Size Distribution, 1925-1999”, Regional Science and Urban Economics, Vol. 38, No. 4, pp. 330-347.
S. Brakman, H. Garretsen and M. Schramm (2004)
“The Strategic Bombing of German Cities during World War II and Its Impact on City Growth”, Journal of Economic Geography, Vol. 4, No. 2, pp. 201-218.
J.L. Broz (1998)
“The origins of central banking: Solutions to the free-rider problem”, International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 2, pp. 231-268.
T. Brück (2001)
“Mozambique: The Economic Effects of the War”, in F. Stewart and V. Fitzgerald (eds.), War and Underdevelopment. Volume 2: Country Experiences, New York: Oxford University Press.
A. Camacho and C. Rodriguez (2013)
“Firm exit and armed conflict in Colombia”, Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 57, No. 1, pp. 89-116.
R. Cappella Zielinski (2016)
How States Pay for Wars, Ithaca and London: Cornell University Press.
V. Cerra and S.C. Saxena (2008)
“Growth Dynamics: The Myth of Economic Recovery”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 98, No. 1, pp. 439-457.
J.T. Chatagnier and K.C. Kavaklı (2017)
“From Economic Competition to Military Combat: Export Similarity and International Conflict”, Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 61, No. 7, pp. 1510-1536.
F. Christia (2012)
Alliance Formation in Civil Wars, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
M. Chupilkin and Zs. Koczan (2022)
“The economic consequences of war: Estimates using synthetic controls”, EBRD working paper, forthcoming.
P. Collier (1999)
“On the Economic Consequences of Civil War”, Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 51, No. 1, pp. 168-183.
D.C. Copeland (2015)
Economic Interdependence and War, Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.
R. Cowan and D. Foray (1995)
“Quandaries in the Economics of Dual Technologies and Spillovers from Military to Civilian Research and Development”, Western University Department of Economics Research Report No. 9509.
D. Davis and D. Weinstein (2002)
“Bones, Bombs, and Break Points: The Geography of Economic Activity”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 92, No. 5, pp. 1269-1289.
D. Davis and D. Weinstein (2008)
“A Search for Multiple Equilibria in Urban Industrial Structure”, Journal of Regional Science, Vol. 48, No. 1, pp. 29-65.
M. Deleidi and M. Mazzucato (2021)
“Directed innovation policies and the supermultiplier: An empirical assessment of mission-oriented policies in the US economy”, Research Policy, Vol. 50, No. 2.
G. Di Giovanni and L. Chelleri (2017)
“Sustainable disaster resilience? Tensions between socio-economic recovery and built environment post-disaster reconstruction in Abruzzo (Italy)”, in S. Deppisch (ed.), Urban Regions Now & Tomorrow: Between vulnerability, resilience and transformation, Wiesbaden: Springer.
EBRD (2020)
Transition Report 2020-21 – The State Strikes Back, London.
B. Eichengreen (2011)
“Lessons from the Marshall Plan”, background paper for the World Bank’s World Development Report 2011.
J. Feigenbaum, J. Lee and F. Mezzanotti (2019)
“Capital Destruction and Economic Growth: the Effects of Sherman’s March, 1850-1920”, NBER Working Paper No. 25392.
A. Field (2008)
“The Impact of the Second World War on US Productivity Growth”, The Economic History Review, Vol. 61, No. 3, pp. 672-694.
V.P. Fortna and R. Huang (2012)
“Democratization after Civil War: A Brush-Clearing Exercise”, International Studies Quarterly, Vol. 56, No. 4, pp. 801-808.
S.E. Gent and M.J.C. Crescenzi (2021)
Market power politics: War, institutions, and strategic delay in world politics, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
C.D. Goldin (1991)
“The role of World War II in the rise of women’s employment”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 81, No. 4, pp. 741-756.
C. Goodhart, F. Capie and N. Schnadt (1994)
“The Development of Central Banking”, in F. Capie, C. Goodhart, S. Fischer and N. Schnadt (eds.), The Future of Central Banking, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
S. Grimm (2008)
“External Democratization after War: Success and Failure”, Democratization, Vol. 15, No. 3, pp. 525 549.
D.P. Gross and B.N. Sampat (2020)
“The World War II Crisis Innovation Model: What Was It, and Where Does It Apply?”, NBER Working Paper No. 27909.
E.J. Hamilton (1950)
“Origin and Growth of the National Debt in France and England”, in Studi in onore di Gino Luzzatto, Vol. 2, Milan: Giuffre.
C. Hendrix (2017)
“Charismatic megafauna in conflict studies, or why WWII is the giant panda of the conflict/security field”, Political Violence at a Glance – Denver Dialogues, 21 November.
A. Hoeffler and M. Reynal-Querol (2003)
“Measuring the costs of conflict”, mimeo.
A. Ichino and R. Winter‐Ebmer (2004)
“The Long‐Run Educational Cost of World War II”, Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 22, No. 1, pp. 57-87.
E. Ilzetski (2020)
“Government Purchases and Plant-Level Productivity: Evidence from World War II”, working paper.
P. Justino (2011)
“Violent Conflict and Human Capital Accumulation”, IDS Working Paper No. 379, Institute of Development Studies.
P. Justino, I. Cardona, R. Mitchell and C. Müller (2012)
“Quantifying the impact of women’s participation in post-conflict economic recovery”, HiCN Working Paper No. 131, Institute of Development Studies.
S. Kang and J. Meernik (2005)
“Civil war destruction and the prospects for economic growth”, The Journal of Politics, Vol. 67, No. 1, pp. 88-109.
L. Klapper, C. Richmond and T. Tran (2015)
“Civil conflict and firm performance: Evidence from Côte d’Ivoire”, mimeo, January. Available at: http://cega.berkeley.edu/assets/miscellaneous_files/63-ABCA_-_Civil_Conflict_and_Firm_Performance.pdf (last accessed on 2 August 2022).
J. Klugman and T. Mukhtarova (2020)
“How did conflict affect women’s economic opportunities in sub-Saharan Africa?”, Georgetown Institute for Women, Peace and Security.
J.-W. Lee and H. Lee (2016)
“Human Capital in the Long Run”, Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 122, pp. 147-169.
J. Manyika, W.H. McRaven and A. Segal (2019)
“Innovation and national security: Keeping our edge”, Independent Task Force Report No. 77.
H. Matsunaga (2019)
“The Reconstruction of Iraq after 2003: Learning from its Successes and Failures”, MENA Development Report, World Bank.
E. McGrattan and L. Ohanian (1999)
“The Macroeconomic Effects of Big Fiscal Shocks: the Case of World War II”, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Working Paper No. 599.
N. Menon and Y. Van der Meulen Rodgers (2015)
“War and women’s work: Evidence from the conflict in Nepal”, Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 59, No. 1, pp. 51-73.
E. Moretti, C. Steinwender and J. Van Reenen (2019)
“The Intellectual Spoils of War? Defense R&D, Productivity and International Spillovers”, NBER Working Paper No. 26483.
D.C. North and B.R. Weingast (1989)
“Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England”, The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 49, No. 4, pp. 803-832.
G. Parker (1972)
The Army of Flanders and the Spanish Road, 1567-1659, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
P. Petesch (2012)
“The clash of violent conflict, good jobs, and gender norms in four economies”, background paper for the World Bank’s World Development Report 2013.
J. Plender (2003)
“The Sinews of War”, Financial Times, 20 March.
P. Poast (2006)
The Economics of War, New York: McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
P. Poast (2015)
“Central Banks at War”, International Organisation, Vol. 69, No. 1, pp. 63-95.
M. Pohl (1994)
Handbook on the History of European Banks, Aldershot: Edward Elgar.
D. Queralt (2018)
“The legacy of war on fiscal capacity”, mimeo.
L. Rapping (1965)
“Learning and World War II Production Functions”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 47, No. 1, pp. 81-86.
C.M. Reinhart and K.S. Rogoff (2009)
This Time Is Different, Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.
D. Rodrik (1999)
“Where Did All the Growth Go? External Shocks, Social Conflict, and Growth Collapses”, Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 4, No. 4, pp. 385-412.
E.K. Rose (2018)
“The rise and fall of female labor force participation during World War II in the United States”, The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 78, No. 3, pp. 673-711.
V. Ruttan (2006)
Is War Necessary for Economic Growth? Military Procurement and Technology Development, New York: Oxford University Press.
Z.O. Saeed, A. Almukhtar and K. Salih (2021)
“Construction beyond war: Assessing time and cost of prefabrication in rebuilding post-disaster cities”, IOP Conference Series: Materials Science and Engineering, Vol. 1090.
M.R. Sarkees (2007)
“The COW Typology of War: Defining and Categorizing Wars (Version 4 of the Data)”.
H. Schweiger (2022)
“Armed conflict and firm performance: Evidence from the 2008 Georgia-Russia conflict”, mimeo.
M.M. Schweitzer (1980)
“World War II and female labor force participation rates”, The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 40, No. 1, pp. 89-95.
P.E. Shea and P. Poast (2018)
“War and default”, Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 62, No. 9, pp. 1876-1904.
M. Shehabi (2020)
“An extraordinary recovery: Kuwait following the Gulf War”, University of Western Australia Discussion Paper No. 15.20.
Special Inspector General for Afghanistan Reconstruction (2021)
“What we need to learn: Lessons from twenty years of Afghanistan reconstruction”, Arlington, Virginia.
J. Stowsky (2004)
“Secrets to shield or share? New dilemmas for military R&D policy in the digital age”, Research Policy, Vol. 33, No. 2, pp. 257-269.
C. Tilly (1985)
“War Making and State Making as Organized Crime”, in P.B. Evans, D. Rueschemeyer and T. Skocpol (eds.), Bringing the State Back In, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
C. Tilly (1990)
Coercion, Capital and European States, AD 990-1992, Oxford: Blackwell Publishing.
R.H. Timberlake Jr (1993)
Monetary Policy in the United States: An Intellectual and Institutional History, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
UNDP (2018)
“Human Development Report, 2018 Statistical Update”, New York.